Intermediate Microeconomics Module 1 Preferences and Indifference Curves

Explore the Intermediate Microeconomics Module 1 Preferences and Indifference Curves study material pdf and utilize it for learning all the covered concepts as it always helps in improving the conceptual knowledge.

Subjects

Social Studies

Grade Levels

K12

Resource Type

PDF

Intermediate Microeconomics Module 1 Preferences and Indifference Curves PDF Download

PREFERENCE AND INDIFFERENCE CURVES CHAPTER Preference and Indifference Curves Er Up by is licensed under THE POLICY QUESTION IS A TAX CREDIT ON HYBRID CAR PURCHASES THE GOVERNMENT BEST CHOICE TO REDUCE FUEL CONSUMPTION AND CARBON EMISSIONS ?

The US government , concerned about the dependence on imported foreign oil and the release of carbon into the atmosphere , has enacted policies where consumers can receive substantial tax credits toward the purchase of certain models of and hybrid cars . This credit may seem like a good policy choice , but it is a costly one it takes away resources that could be spent on other government policies , and it is not the only approach to decreasing carbon emissions and dependency on fossil fuels . So how do we decide which policy is best ?

Suppose that this tax credit is wildly successful and doubles the average fuel economy of all cars on US roads ( this is clearly not realistic but useful for our subsequent discussions ) What do you think would PATRICK EMERSON happen to the fuel consumption of all US motorists ?

Should the government expect fuel consumption and carbon emissions of US cars to decrease by half in response ?

The answers to these questions are critical when choosing among the policy alternatives . In other words , is offering a subsidy to consumers the most effective way to meet the policy goals of decreased dependency on foreign oil and carbon emissions ?

Are there more is , less to achieve these goals ?

The ability to predict with some accuracy the response of consumers to this policy is vital to determining the merits ofthe policy before millions of federal dollars are spent . Consumption decisions , such as how much automobile fuel to consume , come fundamentally from our likes and dislikes . Human , driven by our preferences , is at the core of economic theory . Since we ca consume everything our hearts desire , we have to make choices , and those choices are based on our preferences . Choosing based on likes and dislikes does not mean that we are preferences may include charitable giving and the happiness of others . In this chapter , we will study preferences in economics . LEARNING OBJECTIVES Fundamental Assumptions about Individual Preferences Learning List and explain the three fundamental assumptions about preferences . Graphing Preferences with Indifference Curves Learning Define and draw an indifference curve . Properties of Indifference Curves Learning Relate the properties of indifference curves to assumptions about preference . Marginal Rate of Substitution Learning Define marginal rate of substitution . Perfect Complements and Perfect Substitutes Learning Use indifference curves to illustrate perfect complements and perfect substitutes . Policy Example Is a Tax Credit on Hybrid Car Purchases the Government Best Choice ?

Learning Objective Apply indifference curves to the policy of a hybrid car tax credit . FUNDAMENTAL ASSUMPTIONS ABOUT INDIVIDUAL PREFERENCES Learning Objective List and explain the three fundamental assumptions about preferences . To build a model that can predict choices when variables change , we need to make some assumptions about the preferences that drive consumer choices . Economics makes three assumptions about

PREFERENCE AND CURVES that are the most basic building blocks of our theory of consumer choice . To introduce these , it is useful to think of collections or bundles of goods . To simplify , let identify two bundles , A and . The way we think of preferences always boils down to comparing two bundles . Even if we are ing among three or more bundles , we can always proceed by comparing pairs and eliminating the lesser bundle until we are left with our choice . When we call something a good , we mean exactly that a consumer likes and enjoys consuming . Something that a consumer might not like we call a bad . The fewer bads consumed , the pier a consumer is . To keep things simple , we will focus only on goods , but it is easy to incorporate bads into the same framework by considering their fewer the bads , the better . The three fundamental assumptions about preferences are the following . Completeness . We say preferences are complete when a consumer can always say one of the following about two bundles . A is preferred to , is preferred to A , or . A is equally good as . We say preferences are transitive if they are internally consistent ifA is preferred to and is preferred to , then it must be that A is preferred to . More is better . If represents more of at least one good and no less of any other good than , then A is preferred to . The most important results of our model of consumer behavior hold when we only assume ness and transitivity , but life is much easier if we assume more is better as well . If we assume free ( we can get rid of extra goods at no cost ) the assumption that more is better seems reasonable . It is certainly the case that more is not worse in that situation , and so to keep things simple , we maintain the standard assumption that we prefer more ofa good than less . Our model works well when these assumptions are valid , which seems to be most of the time in most situations . However , sometimes these assumptions do not apply . For instance , in order to have complete and transitive preferences , we must know something about the goods in the bundle . Imagine an can who does not speak Hindi entering an Indian restaurant where the menu is entirely in Hindi . Without the aid of translation , the customer can not act as economic theory would predict .

PATRICK EMERSON GRAPHING PREFERENCES WITH INDIFFERENCE CURVES Learning Objective Define and draw an indifference curve . Individual preferences , given the basic assumptions , can be represented using something called curves . An indifference curve is a graph of all the combinations of bundles that a consumer prefers equally . In other words , the consumer would be just as happy consuming any of them . preferences graphically is a great way to understand both preferences and how the consumer choice model it is worth mastering them early in your study of . Bundles can contain many goods , but to simplify , we will consider only pairs of goods . At first , this may seem impossibly restrictive , but it turns out that we do really lose generality in so doing . We can always consider one good in the pair to be , collectively , all other consumption goods . What the goods restriction does so well is to help us see the in consuming more of one good and less of another . Sandwiches per week Burritos per week Figure . and Indifference curves Figure is a graph with two goods on the axes the weekly consumption of burritos and the weekly consumption of sandwiches for a college student . In the middle ofthe graph is point A , which represents a bundle of both burritos ( read from the horizontal axis ) and sandwiches ( read from the vertical axis ) Now we can ask what bundles are better , worse , or the same in terms of satisfying this college student . Clearly , bundles that contain fewer of both goods , like ) are worse than A , or ' because they violate the assumption . Equally clear is that bundles that contain more of both goods , like , are better than A , and because they satisfy the assumption . To create an indifference curve , we want to identify bundles that this college student is indifferent about consuming . Ifa bundle has more burritos , the student will have to have fewer sandwiches and vice versa . By finding all the bundles that are just as good as A , like and , and connecting them with a line , we create an indifference curve , like the one in the middle .

PREFERENCE AND CURVES Notice that figure includes several indifference curves . Each curve represents a different level of overall satisfaction that the student can achieve via bundles . A curve farther out from the origin represents a higher level of satisfaction than a curve closer to the origin . Notice also that these curves share a number of characteristics they slope downward , they do not cross , and they are all explore these properties in more detail in the next section . PROPERTIES OF INDIFFERENCE CURVES Learning Objective Relate the properties of indifference curves to assumptions about preference . As introduced in section , indifference curves have three key properties . They are downward sloping . They do not cross . They are bowed in ( a way of saying they are convex to the origin ) For simplicity and clarity , from here on , we will describe preferences that lead to indifference curves with these three properties as standard . This will be our default consumers have standard preferences unless otherwise noted . As we will see in this chapter , there are other types of preferences that are common as well , and we will continue to study both the standard type and the other types as we progress through the material . Sandwiches Burritos Figure indifference curves violating the ' assumption To understand the first two properties , it useful to think about what would happen if they were not true .

PATRICK EMERSON Sandwiches Burritos Figure Crossing violating the transitivity assumption Think about indifference curves that slope upward , as in figure . In this case , we have two bundles on the same indifference curve , A and , but has more of both burritos and sandwiches than does A . 50 this violates the assumption of more is better . More is better implies indifference curves are downward sloping . Similarly , consider figure . In this figure , there are two indifference curves that cross . Now consider bundle A on one of the indifference curves . It represents more of both goods than bundle , which lies on the other indifference curve . Because bundle lies on the same indifference curve as bundle , the two bundles should be equally preferred , and therefore A should be preferred to and Bundle also represents more of both goods than bundle , and therefore should be preferred to ever , is on the same indifference curve as A , so should be preferred to A . Since A ca be to and preferred to A at the same time , this is a violation of our assumptions of transitivity and more is better . Transitivity and more is better imply that indifference curves do not cross . Now we come to the third property indifference curves bow in . This property comes from a fourth assumption about preferences , which we can add to the assumptions discussed in section . Consumers like variety .

PREFERENCE AND CURVES Sandwiches Figure Preference for variety resulting in curves The assumption that consumers prefer variety is not necessary but still applies in many situations . For example , most consumers would probably prefer to eat both sandwiches and burritos during a week and not just one or the other ( remember , this is for consumers who consider them both like them ) In fact , if you had only sandwiches to eat for a week , you probably be willing to give up a lot of sandwiches for a few burritos and vice versa . If you had reasonably equal amounts of both , be willing to trade one for the other , but at closer to ratios . Notice that if we graph this , we naturally get indifference curves , as shown in figure . Preference for variety implies that indifference curves are bowed in . Remember these three key points about preferences and indifference curves . More is better implies indifference curves are downward sloping . Transitivity and more is better imply indifference curves do not cross . variety implies that indifference curves are bowed in . MARGINAL RATE OF SUBSTITUTION Learning Objective Define marginal rate of substitution . From now on , we will assume that consumers like variety and that indifference curves are bowed in . However , it is worth considering examples on either extreme perfect substitutes and perfect . When we move along an indifference curve , we can think of a consumer substituting one good for another . Two bundles on the same indifference curve , which represents the same satisfaction from sumption , have one thing in common they represent more ofone good and less ofthe other . This makes sense given our assumption of more is better if more of one good makes you better off , then you must have less of the other good in order to maintain the same level of satisfaction .

PATRICK EMERSON In economics , we have a more technical way of expressing this the marginal rate of ( The is the number of units of one good a consumer is willing to give up to get one more unit ofanother good and maintain the same level of satisfaction . This is one ofthe most important concepts in economics because it is critical to understanding consumer choice . Mathematically , we express the marginal rate of substitution for two generic goods like this AA AB where A indicates a change in the quantity of the good . In the case ofour student consuming burritos and sandwiches , the expression would be . For example , suppose at his current consumption bundle , five burritos and four sandwiches weekly , Luca is willing to give up two burritos to get one more sandwich . Another way of saying the same thing is that Luca is indifferent between consuming five burritos and four sandwiches in a week or three burritos and five sandwiches in a week . The for Luca at that point is . Sandwiches Burritos Figure rate for burritos and sandwiches Note that the is negative because it represents a more sandwiches for fewer burritos . Notice that figure illustrates a change in the good on the vertical axis ( sandwiches ) over the change in the good on the horizontal axis ( burritos ) This is the same as saying the rise over the run . From this discussion and graph , it should be clear that the is the same as the slope ofthe curve at any given point along it .

PREFERENCE AND CURVES PERFECT COMPLEMENTS AND PERFECT SUBSTITUTES Learning Objective Use indifference curves to illustrate perfect complements and perfect . We have now studied the assumptions upon which our model of consumer behavior is built . Completeness . Transitivity . More is better . Love of variety It is worth taking a moment to think about two other types of preference relations that are special cases but not uncommon perfect complements and perfect substitutes . Perfect Complements Perfect complements are goods that consumers want to consume only in fixed proportions . Consider the example ofan iPod and earphones . An iPod is useless without earphones , and earphones are useless without an iPod , but put them together , and voila , you have a portable stereo , which is worth quite a lot . An extra set of earphones does increase the usefulness of the iPod , and an extra iPod does increase the usefulness of the earphones . So these are things that we consume in a fixed tion one iPod goes with one set of earphones . We call such preference relations perfect complements . Figure illustrates the process of drawing indifference curves for perfect complements . Ipod Figure curves for goods that are perfect complements In figure , when we start with a bundle of one iPod and one set of earbuds ( as in bundle A ) what are the other bundles that are just as good to the consumer ?

Two sets of earbuds and one iPod is no better 10 PATRICK EMERSON than one set of earbuds and one iPod , so bundle lies on the same indifference curve . The same is true for two iPods and one set of earbuds , as in bundle From this example , we can see that curves for perfect complements have right angles . Perfect Substitutes A perfect substitute is a good that makes a as well a fixed amount of another good . That is , one unit of one good is just as good as one unit of another good . Both Morton and Diamond Crystal are brands of table salt . For most consumers , a teaspoon of one salt is always just as good as a teaspoon of the other . We call goods like these perfect substitutes . 10 10 Figure curves that are perfect Drawing indifference curves for perfect substitutes is straightforward , as shown in figure . in figure contains five teaspoons of each type of salt . This isjust as good to the consumer as a bundle with ten teaspoons of Morton salt and zero teaspoons of Diamond Crystal , as in bundle . It is as good as the ten teaspoons of Diamond Crystal and zero teaspoons of Morton in bundle .

PREFERENCE AND CURVES 11 Good Good Figure The relationship between indifference curves for standard preferences and perfect and substitutes You can think of perfect complements and perfect substitutes as polar extremes of preference relations . Figure shows how a typical indifference curve lies between perfect complements and perfect . You should understand , when graphically represented , that the indifference curve for standard preferences lies between perfect complements and perfect substitutes . POLICY EXAMPLE IS A TAX CREDIT ON HYBRID CAR PURCHASES THE GOVERNMENT BEST CHOICE TO REDUCE FUEL CONSUMPTION AND CARBON EMISSIONS ?

Learning Objective Apply indifference curves to the policy of a hybrid car tax credit . The issue of consumer preferences is central to the policy question posed at the beginning ofthis chapter .

12 PATRICK EMERSON Traffic jam from on is licensed under Recall that we are assuming that the tax credit will cause the average fuel economy of US cars to double . So from a consumer behavior perspective , one of the things we want to know in evaluating the policy is whether this improvement in gas mileage will cause an equivalent decrease in the demand for gasoline . In other words , the consumer decision is about the of purchasing gasoline to travel in a car sus all the other uses of the money spent on gas .

PREFERENCE AND CURVES 13 Miles Driven Figure curve for miles driven versus money spent on We can apply the principle of preferences and the assumptions we make about them to this particular question by drawing indifference curves , as shown in figure . We can label one axis of the indifference curve map miles driven and the other money for other consumption . Doing so illustrates how confining ourselves to only two dimensions is really not that fining at all . By considering the other axis as money for all other purchases , we are really looking at the general between one particular consumption good and everything else that a consumer could possibly consume . So what would our indifference curve look like ?

As before , it would be downward more by car affords the consumer more freedom of movement and therefore more consumption choices , both of which are goods . The indifference curves would not cross for the same reasons discussed in section . But what about the principle of more is better ?

The point here is to again think about the principle of free disposal as long as the ability to drive more miles is not bad ( and it is hard to imagine how it could be ) then more miles are never worse . The remaining question is whether the preference for variety is a good assumption in this case . It is helpful to consider the extremes for those consumers who own cars , never driving any miles is probably not very practical . Likewise , spending one entire income only on expenses relating to driving one car

14 PATRICK EMERSON is unappealing . A good assumption , then , is that most people with a car would prefer some combination of miles driven and other consumption to either extreme and we can draw our indifference curves as convex to the origin . We are not yet in a position to say much about the policy itself , but we have one piece of the model we will use to analyze it . With this indifference curve , we can move onto the other pieces of the model that we will study in chapters , and . EXPLORING THE POLICY QUESTION . Suppose that a typical consumer is concerned about how their individual driving habits are negatively impacting the environment . How might such a change in attitude change the shape of the consumer indifference curves ?

REVIEW TOPICS AND RELATED LEARNING OUTCOMES Fundamental Assumptions about Individual Preferences Learning List and explain the three fundamental assumptions about preferences . Graphing Preferences with Indifference Curves Learning Define and draw an indifference curve . Properties of Indifference Curves Learning Relate the properties of indifference curves to assumptions about preference . Marginal Rate of Substitution Learning Define marginal rate of substitution . Perfect Complements and Perfect Substitutes Learning Use indifference curves to illustrate perfect complements and perfect substitutes . Policy Example Is a Tax Credit on Hybrid Car Purchases the Government Best Choice to Reduce Fuel Consumption and Carbon Emissions ?

Learning Objective Apply indifference curves to the policy of a hybrid car tax credit .

PREFERENCE AND INDIFFERENCE CURVES 15 LEARN KEY TOPICS Terms Completeness We say preferences are complete when a consumer can always say one of the following about two bundles A is preferred to , is preferred to A , or A is equally good as Transitivity We say preferences are transitive if they are internally consistent ifA is preferred to and is preferred to , then it must be that A is to More is Better If bundle A represents more of at least one good and no less of any other good than bundle , then A is preferred to Indifference Curve A graph of all the combinations of bundles that a consumer prefers equally . In other words , the consumer would bejust as happy consuming any of them . Marginal Rate of Substitution ( The is the number of units of one good a consumer is willing to give up to get one more unit of another good and maintain the same level of satisfaction . Perfect Complements Goods that consumers want to consume only in proportions , to an iPhone . Perfect Substitutes A good that makes a consumer just as well off as a amount of another good , Morton and Diamond Crystal are brands of table salt . For most consumers , a teaspoon of one salt is as good as a teaspoon of the other . Graphs Indifference Curve Sandwiches per week Burritos per week Bundles and Curves

16 PATRICK EMERSON Marginal Rate of Substitution Sandwiches Burritos Figure Marginal rare for burritos and sandwiches Perfect Complements Figure Perfect Complements Perfect Substitutes PREFERENCE AND CURVES Figure . Substitutes Good Good Figure The between Standard Preference , and Substitutes Equations Marginal Rate of Substitution ( AA 17